Since the 1980s, a widespread view has arisen in the literature that the post-1950 economic successes of Taiwan and the Republic of Korea have been due, in part at least, to the legacy of Japanese colonialism. This paper challenges that view by comparing Japanese economic achievements in both Taiwan and Korea with those of the British, French, Dutch and Americans in their Southeast Asian colonies. The paper examines the record of economic growth and structural change across the various colonies, and also discusses policies relating to government revenue and expenditure and to trade, exchange rates and the balance of payments. The paper also looks at some non-monetary indicators relating to living standards, including mortality rates and educational enrolments. The main conclusion is that the facts do not wholly support the case for Japanese exceptionalism.
“Japan has always been growth-oriented, in colonial areas as well as at home; and it is clear that Japanese rule helped to initiate intensive growth in both Korea and Taiwan” (Reynolds 1983: 956)
In the second part of the twentieth century, the two former Japanese colonies of Taiwan and the Republic of Korea have ‘forged ahead’ in the race for economic growth, and have achieved considerable success in narrowing the gap in per capita GDP between themselves and both the USA and Japan.[1] Aside from the two city states of Hong Kong and Singapore, no other former colony in Asia has achieved the same success in catching up. In several, including India, Indonesia and the Philippines, per capita GDP was lower in relation to that of the USA (and in the case of India and Indonesia in relation to that of their former coloniser) in 2000 than it had been in 1913 (Tables 1 and 2). Until the 1980s, most scholars wishing to explain the post-1950 growth of both Taiwan and the Republic of Korea stressed the policies adopted by the governments which had obtained power after the end of Japanese colonialism. Most Korean scholars viewed the Japanese era with abhorrence, and while this was less the case in Taiwan, those seeking reasons for the remarkable growth and transformation which occurred after 1950 in the Republic of China were inclined to stress post-1950 policy changes, especially in land reform and trade and industrialization policy, although several writers did emphasize the Japanese record in promoting technological change in rice agriculture (Myers and Ching 1964; Myers 1969; Myers 1970; Hayami 1973; Carr and Myers 1973; Thorbecke 1979).
The Japanese Empire, 1895-1932
By the early 1980s, a ‘revisionist’ school was becoming more influential, which tried to analyse in more depth the policies followed by the Japanese in both colonies and the extent to which they laid the foundations for the rapid growth and structural transformation which occurred after 1950. The seminal collection of essays edited by Myers and Peattie (1984) had a particularly important impact in the English-speaking world. In his introductory chapter, Peattie pointed out that Japanese colonial officials tended to model their policies on the ‘superbly successful modernization effort which Japan itself had undertaken in the three decades after the Meiji leadership had overthrown the Tokugawa feudal order’ (Peattie 1984: 23). According to Peattie, the conditions in both Taiwan and Korea when the Japanese took over were not greatly different from those in Japan in the late 1860s; they were static peasant societies whose small ruling elites were corrupt and inefficient and largely resistant to change. Apart from consolidation of military and political power in their hands, the colonisers set themselves the twin goals of agricultural expansion and transformation of social attitudes through expanding the educational system. By the 1930s, as Japanese imperial ambitions expanded to take in much of China, and ultimately Southeast Asia as well, the industrial sectors of both colonies were also developed to provide essential inputs into the Japanese war economy.
To many subsequent scholars seeking to find a reason for the superior performance of Taiwan and the Republic of Korea, Japanese colonialism did indeed appear more developmental in both its aims and achievements, in comparison with colonial regimes in other parts of Asia. In the case of Taiwan, Amsden (1985: 79-80) continued the emphasis of earlier authors such as Myers on the agricultural transformation brought about by the Japanese, as well as achievements in primary education and the development of infrastructure. On Korea, Cumings put forward the view that ‘the colonial period played an undeniable role in placing Korea above most Third World nations by 1945’ (Cumings 1984a: 481; see also Cumings 1984b), while Kohli (1994) argued that by sweeping aside the rapacious and predatory Yi state, the Japanese were decisive in shaping a political economy that later evolved into the high-growth South Korean path to development. Kohli stressed the reforms in both the civilian bureaucracy and the police which laid the foundations for the post-1945 state. In addition, he discusses the role of the state in industrial development under the Japanese and also Japanese policies aimed at controlling the ‘lower classes’ including both the peasantry and the industrial working class. In fact, according to his analysis, there was a striking degree of institutional continuity between colonial Korea and the South Korean state under Park Chung-Hee (Kohli 1994: 1285).
The arguments of Kohli, and those of other revisionists on Korean development, were subjected to critical review by Haggard, Kang and Moon (1997). They pointed out that there were serious questions about the enduring nature of the Japanese legacy; that the belief in the continuity of the Japanese colonial administrative system displays a ‘technocratic bias’ in that it ignores the importance of the political elites who control the administration; that the evidence that the Korean firms and entrepreneurs who rose to prominence after 1960 had roots in the colonial era was questionable, and that the post-1960 growth performance in Korea was made possible, in part at least, by a reversal of Japanese colonial policies, especially those regarding agrarian reform and education. Other scholars have pointed out that Japanese policies in both Korea and Taiwan were intended first and foremost to serve Japanese interests, and in this respect did not differ from those of colonial powers in other parts of Asia (Howe 2001: 43; see also Chang and Myers 1963: 436).
It is not the purpose of this paper to enter into the debate on the causes of the rapid growth in both Taiwan and South Korea after 1960. My purpose is rather to look at the record of other colonial regimes in Southeast Asia and to place the debate over Japanese colonialism in a wider perspective. By reviewing the record in British, Dutch, French and American colonial possessions, I argue that we are in a better position to assess the colonial legacies bequeathed to independent states. [2] The key question posed in the paper is the following. Was the difference in economic performance, and in broader development indicators, between the various colonies in East and Southeast Asia sufficiently striking at the end of the 1930s to provide a clear indication of their post-1950 economic trajectories? If the answer is no, then that would support those who argue that it was the process of decolonisation itself, or the policies adopted by post-independence regimes (some of them intended to reverse rather than sustain colonial policies) that have determined the post-1950 outcomes. On the other hand if the evidence suggests that the Japanese colonies were obviously ahead in terms of several development indicators in the late 1930s, then the case for Japanese ‘developmental colonialism’ is supported.
I begin by examining the evidence on economic growth and structural change across colonial territories in East and South East Asia in the first four decades of the 20th century. I then discuss policies relating to government revenue and expenditure and to trade, exchange rates and the balance of payments. I also look at some non-monetary indicators relating to living standards, including mortality rates and educational enrolments The final section draws conclusions on the nature of the colonial state in East and Southeast Asia and the legacies bequeathed by these states to post-colonial governments.
Economic growth and structural change
By 1913, the USA had already become the world leader in terms of both total and per capita GDP (Maddison 2003: Tables 8b, 8c). Of all the major Asian economies, only Japan had a per capita GDP which was more than one quarter of that of the USA; in most of the colonial territories and in China, per capita GDP was well below 20 per cent of that in the USA (Table 1). After Japan, the highest per capita GDP in 1913 was in Hong Kong and Singapore, followed by the Philippines, Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand. South Korea and Taiwan were below all these countries, and above only Burma (Table 3). By 1929, Taiwan and South Korea had overtaken Thailand, but were still below the other three Southeast Asian economies. It was only during the 1930s, a period of slow or negative growth in most parts of Southeast Asia that the two Japanese colonies grew much faster than in other parts of Southeast Asia, although by 1938 the Philippines still had a per capita GDP above either of them.[3]
As would be expected given the generally low levels of per capita GDP in 1913, most Asian economies were predominantly agricultural, with more than 40 per cent of GDP coming from the agricultural sector, except in Japan where the share had already fallen to under 30 per cent (Table 4). In Korea almost 60 per cent of GDP accrued from agriculture and forestry, which was a higher share than in those Southeast Asian countries for which we have estimates, with the exception of Burma (Table 4). Agricultural growth was certainly rapid in both Taiwan and Korea after 1913, and by 1938 value added in agriculture had doubled in Taiwan and almost doubled in Korea. The performance in Thailand, Indonesia and Burma was not as impressive, mainly because of the very slow growth in the 1930s. In most parts of Asia over these years, the non-agricultural sectors were growing faster than agriculture, so that by 1938 the agricultural share of GDP had fallen everywhere except in Thailand. In Indonesia by 1938, agriculture accounted for about one third of total GDP, compared with 35 per cent in Taiwan and 41 per cent in Korea. By the 1930s, non-agricultural employment had also become significant in several parts of Asia. In Japan, over half the economically active population was working outside agriculture; in Indonesia, Burma and the Philippines the proportion was around 30 per cent. This was a higher ratio than in Taiwan and Korea (Table 5).
The rapid agricultural growth in both Korea and Taiwan after 1913 was largely based on smallholder agriculture, albeit with a high incidence of tenancy. Estate agriculture was unfamiliar to the Japanese, and the colonial officials felt comfortable with the landlord-tenant regimes which existed in both colonies, and saw little reason to change them (Ho 1984: 385). After the serious shortages and rice riots of 1918, the Japanese government began to facilitate the transfer of Japanese high yielding rice varieties to both Taiwan and Korea, in the hope that both colonies could provide Japan with rice. Farmers’ associations and agricultural cooperatives were established; they appear to have functioned more successfully in Taiwan than in Korea (Thorbecke 1979: 137). The ponlai variety in particular diffused rapidly, and fertiliser use increased in both colonies (Hayami 1973: Table 2.1; Myers and Yamada 1984: 437-9). Government investment in irrigation also grew, which led to an increase in double cropping especially in Taiwan.
By 1925, Korea was supplying Japan with over five per cent of its total rice consumption, and Taiwan a further 2.8 per cent; both these percentages increased over the 1930s (Ka 1995: 135). Taiwan also became an important supplier of sugar to Japan, displacing imports from Java, although the development of the Taiwanese sugar industry was assisted by a variety of direct and indirect subsidies (Ho 1971: 320-23; Lin 1973: 15-17; Schneider 1998: 164). There can be little doubt that the introduction of a “Meiji agrarian strategy”, including considerable investment in irrigation and rural infrastructure, and the large market in metropolitan Japan all served to accelerate the pace of agricultural growth in both Korea and Taiwan, and by the late 1930s, rice yields were much higher than in other parts of Asia (Table 6). The impact of Japanese agrarian policies on the welfare of the rural populations in both colonies was more controversial, and will be discussed below.
In much of Southeast Asia after 1900, colonial governments were also actively seeking to promote agricultural growth, both for home and foreign markets. The growth of rice production was quite rapid in the decades after 1910 in land abundant parts of Southeast Asia such as the Philippines, Malaya and Thailand, and in southern Vietnam (Cochinchina), although nowhere was it faster than in Taiwan (Table 6). Much of this growth was due to the reproduction of traditional varieties and technologies over more land, but some colonial governments, notably the Dutch in Java, did try to develop new varieties which increased double cropping, and thus annual production (Barker and Herdt 1985: 58; van der Eng 1996: 81-91). In Peninsular Malaya, in Sumatra, and in southern Vietnam, the English, Dutch and French colonial authorities facilitated the acquisition of land by large estate companies to grow crops such as tobacco and rubber. The expansion of rubber estates after 1900 in Sumatra and Malaya in turn led to a rapid growth in smallholder production, so that by the late 1930s almost half of all rubber production came from small producers (Booth 2004: Table 10). Much of the rubber went not to markets in the metropolitan powers but to the USA. This growth of both estate and smallholder export production in response to the opportunities offered by world market demand had no counterpart in either Taiwan or Korea, where export growth was tightly geared to the requirements of the Japanese market.
Turning from agricultural to industrial growth, there were differences between the two Japanese colonies both in growth of the manufacturing between 1911 and 1938, and in the size of the sector by the late 1930s. From a very small base in 1911, industrial growth in Korea was more rapid than in mainland Japan; between 1911 and 1938, there was an almost ten-fold increase in value added from the mining and manufacturing sectors. Growth was particularly rapid over the 1930s, and by 1938, manufacturing and mining accounted for around 16 per cent of Korean net domestic product. In Taiwan, industrial growth was slower, especially over the 1930s, but because the manufacturing and mining sector was larger to begin with, it accounted for a greater share of net domestic product than in Korea, around 24 per cent by 1938 (Mizoguchi and Umemura 1988: 231-39). In Korea, the growth in the 1930s has been attributed to the establishment of large capital-intensive plants by Japanese zaibatsu including Mitsui, Mitsubishi and Sumitomo in sectors such as chemicals, metals and textiles (Grajdanzev 1944: 152-171; see also Ho 1984: 364-69 and Woo 1991: 35). Industrial development appears to have been more capital intensive in Korea, so that the percentage of the labour force employed in industry was lower (Table 5). Suh (1978: 47-51) argues that total employment in manufacturing actually fell in absolute terms over the 1930s; this was entirely due to a very sharp decline in the employment of women. [4]
It is often asserted that, right up until 1940, the industrialisation which took place in South East Asia was largely restricted to agricultural and mineral processing. British, French and Dutch colonial regimes were supposedly intent on preserving colonial markets for their own manufactures, and had little interest in encouraging either their own nationals or anyone else to establish industrial plants in their colonies. In fact the evidence does not support these rather crude generalisations, especially in the inter-war era. The increase in national income which undeniably took place between 1900 and 1930 in British Malaya, Indonesia and the Philippines, and to a lesser extent in Burma and Indochina did lead to increased demand for a range of manufactures, some of which by reason of high transport costs or perishability could profitably be produced in the home market, even without tariff protection.
The world slump of the 1930s had a serious impact on agricultural exports (both in terms of quantity and price) in most parts of South East Asia, and forced many colonial officials to consider economic diversification as a means of insulating their populations against the vagaries of world markets. “Among the solutions offered none was seized upon with more enthusiasm than industrialisation” (Shepherd 1941: 4). The flood of manufactured exports from Japan also served to increase official support for colonial industrialisation; after all if Japan could industrialise using its abundant supplies of cheap labour, why not Java, Luzon or Vietnam? Already by 1930, the industrial labour force accounted for more than ten per cent of total employment in British Malaya, Burma, Indonesia and the Philippines (Table 5). Much of this employment was in small-scale and cottage industry, but the estimates of van der Eng (2002: 171) indicate that value added in the industrial sector (manufacturing, utilities and construction) in Indonesia comprised around fifteen per cent of GDP in 1930. During the 1930s, the Dutch made great efforts to attract foreign investment into the large-scale manufacturing sector, with considerable success. Companies such as Goodyear, National Carbon, Unilever and Bata all built Indonesian plants during the decade, and in addition breweries, paper mills, canneries and several large weaving and spinning mills were established (Booth 1998: 44). By 1941, the industrial sector (manufacturing, utilities and construction) accounted for around 20 per cent of GDP (van der Eng 2002: 172).
Although French policies in Indo-china were not supportive of industrialisation which might compete with French imports, official attitudes began to change in the inter-war years, especially with regard to yarn and textiles. In densely settled Tonkin, concern about rural unemployment led to some support for both the spinning and weaving industry, which also assisted small producers. A government survey of 1940 found that Tonkin had 55,000 weavers, and a total of 120,000 textile workers (Norlund 1991: 86-89; see also Shepherd 1941: 30-31). In the Philippines, much of the industry which developed until 1918 was based on agricultural and mineral processing, although considerable diversification occurred during the 1920s. By 1939, the manufacture of clothing and embroideries, together with “native textiles” employed almost 170,000 workers according to that year’s Population Census, the great majority women. Manufacturing industry as a whole employed over 11 per cent of all workers (Kurihara 1945: 16-17). By the 1930s, Philippine officials were arguing that only complete autonomy in tariff matters would allow the Philippines to industrialise (Espino 1933: 11-12). But even under a tariff system which gave most American manufactures duty-free access to the local market, manufacturing industry accounted for around 21 per cent of gross value added in 1938 (Hooley 1968: Tables 1 and 3).
Anti-Japanese fighters in Korea, circa 1910
The evidence would hardly seem to constitute an overwhelming case for “Japanese colonial exceptionalism” on grounds of economic growth leading to rapid structural change away from agriculture and towards industry and the modern services sector. Per capita GDP growth was quite rapid in both Taiwan and Korea in the twenty five years from 1913 to 1938, but it only outpaced that in Southeast Asia after 1929, where the effects of the world crisis of the early 1930s were more severe. Certainly the growth in rice output and yields was impressive, especially in Taiwan, but rice output also grew rapidly in some of the land abundant parts of South East Asia. Neither does it appear that industrial growth was more rapid in Taiwan and Korea than in some parts of South East Asia. In fact Taiwan ressembled economies such as the Philippines, Indonesia and British Malaya in that industrialisation was very largely based on agricultural processing, at least until the 1930s. In Korea, industrial growth was rapid, but from a very low base, and the acceleration during the 1930s was largely the result of investment in heavy industry by Japanese conglomerates. There were parallels with Indonesia, where there was also quite rapid growth in manufacturing industry based on investment from foreign multinationals in the latter part of the 1930s. It seems probable that by 1940, industry accounted for roughly the same share of gross domestic production in both Korea and Indonesia, although it employed a higher share of the labour force in Indonesia. One historian of Korea has claimed that “colonial industrial growth was a powerful historical earthquake” (Park 1999: 158). If that was the case, earthquakes of a similar or stronger force were also felt in several parts of South East Asia.
What were governments doing? The myth of the nightwatchman state
One of the enduring concepts of colonial states in many parts of Asia is that they were almost entirely concerned with maintaining law and order, and with raising the revenues necessary to support the costs of such activities. Colonial states were considered to be ‘nightwatchman states’ with ‘no self-conscious programme of active economic development’ (Morris 1963: 615). Those writers who support Japanese exceptionalism argue that the Japanese colonies were characterised by more activist governments; in the case of Korea, Kohli (2004: 40) argues:
The colonial state in Korea was a busy state. While pursuing the imperial interests of Japan, it evolved a full policy agenda, including the goal of Korea’s economic transformation. The broad strategy of transformation was two-pronged: The state utilized its bureaucratic capacities to directly undertake numerous economic tasks, and, more important, the state involved propertied groups- both in the countryside and in the cities, and both Japanese and Koreans- in production-oriented alliances aimed at achieving sustained economic change.
But was such a policy agenda unique to Korea? In fact, by the first decade of the twentieth century, all the colonial powers in South East Asia had established effective administrative structures which prioritised the reform of fiscal systems. Independent Thailand also carried out reforms of government revenue policy after 1892 (Ingram 1971: Chapter 8). The metropolitan powers wanted tax systems under the direct control of colonial administrations, which would be sufficiently buoyant to fund both current expenditures and provide a surplus for investment. Old practices of revenue farming were eliminated over the last decades of the nineteenth century, in favour of more diversified systems relying not just on land taxes but also on export and import duties, excises, sales taxes and in some cases corporate and individual income taxes[5]. Both Ho (1984: 357-8) and Kohli (2004: 42-43) have discussed the reforms of revenues systems which followed upon the Japanese occupation of Taiwan and Korea, including reformed land taxes following the Meiji model. But in other parts of Asia, colonial regimes were going even further in increasing total revenues and diversifying revenue sources.
By 1910, government revenues per capita were highest in the Federated Malay States, where export duties already accounted for around 30 per cent of total government receipts and land taxes a further eight percent (Fraser 1939: Appendix A). Revenues from monopolies including the sale of opium were also important as they were in the Straits Settlements, where by 1910, per capita revenues were roughly the same as in Taiwan, and much higher than in Korea. Revenues per capita in Korea did increase quite rapidly after 1910, and were around the same (in dollar terms) as in the Philippines and Burma by 1929 (Table 7). The proportion of revenues derived from the land tax and from import duties fell in Korea after 1911, as other forms of taxation and non-tax revenues including monopoly profits increased (Kimura 1989: Table 5). Kimura argues that the lack of progessivity in the revenue system favoured higher income groups including industrialists and senior officials, most of whom were Japanese. By the latter part of the 1930s, both Taiwan and Korea were still dependent on non-tax revenues, including revenues from monopolies for around half of government revenues (Table 8). Several Southeast Asian colonies, including the Philippines, Burma and Indonesia were more dependent on tax revenues. This did not necessarily mean a more progressive tax system, although it is probable that in those economies where around half of all government revenues were derived from income and land taxes and customs duties, the overall impact of the revenue system was more progressive[6].
A Japanese Government-General building erected in front of
the Gyungbok Palace, the symbol of Korean Royal power.
In discussing the overall incidence of the fiscal system, it is essential to look at expenditures as well as revenues. Broadly speaking, expenditures rose and fell with revenues, reaching a peak in 1929, and falling thereafter in both South East Asia and Taiwan and Korea (Tables 7 and 9). But in most cases, the match was not perfect with expenditures above or below revenues for several years. In the case of Taiwan, expenditures tended to be lower than revenues for most years, and the budget surplus was one factor in the large balance of payments surplus in Taiwan after 1920 (Mizoguchi and Yamamoto 1984: 408-12). In Korea, expenditures and revenues were broadly in balance. In several South East Asian colonies, such as Indonesia, the FMS and the Philippines, budgets swung into deficit in the early 1930s, as revenues fell with falling export receipts and governments found it difficult to cut expenditures at the same rate (Booth 2003: 436-38).
What sorts of expenditures were accorded priority by the different colonial regimes? During the first three decades of the twentieth century, most colonial regimes in South East Asia were devoting a considerable part of their budgets to education, health, agriculture and public works, including irrigation. The comparative study carried out by Schwulst (1932: 57) in 1931 found that the Philippines, the FMS and French Indochina were all spending more than 40 per cent of total budgetary outlays on these sectors. Administrative expenditures, together with defence and debt service, accounted for much of the rest. In Taiwan, expenditures on agriculture, education and public works accounted for over 60 per cent of budgetary outlays for most years from 1910 to 1938. In Korea by contrast, expenditures on public order and administration took up a larger share of budgetary expenditures for much of the period from 1911 to 1938, although government expenditures on transport accounted for around one third of total expenditures by the late 1930s (Mizoguchi and Umemura 1989: 289-93).
It is difficult to generalise about government expenditure priorities in any of the colonial territories in East and South East Asia over the decades from 1900 to 1940. They changed with changing external circumstances, and changing pressures from the metropolitan powers. But the evidence does not support any facile argument that expenditures in the Japanese colonies were more ‘developmental’ in the sense that sectors such as infrastructure, education, or agricultural development were consistently allocated higher shares of total expenditures than in other colonial territories. The record on education and health outcomes is examined below. Here it worth noting that, while by the late 1930s both Taiwan and Korea had high endowments of both roads and railways (relative to area) in comparison with most parts of South East Asia, neither colony was better served than Java, which compared favourably with Taiwan in terms of transport infrastructure (Table 10). British Malaya did well in terms of both roads and electric power capacity. Nowhere in South East Asia was irrigation as extensive as in Korea and Taiwan, although colonial governments in both Indonesia and Vietnam did give irrigation development high priority, and devoted substantial budgetary resources to it until the 1930s.
Trade and exchange rate policies
An influential model of a colonial economy which was developed in the 1960s and 1970s emphasized an open economy which is tightly tied via both trade and investment flows to the metropolitan power, “so that bilateralism may be a more approriate description than openness” (Ho 1984: 381; see also Paauw and Fei 1973: Chapter 1). In such a model, exports were entirely agricultural and mineral and supplied from enclaves which were not tightly linked to the rest of the “hinterland”, where the great majority of the population lived. Imports were determined by the requirements of the export industries for both consumption and capital goods, and were usually well below exports in value, so that a large export surplus could be used to finance outward remittances of profits; part of the export surplus was accumulated as foreign reserves in the metropole. Such reserves were then used to maintain strict parity between the colonial currency and that of the colony via a currency board arrangement. Ho (1984: 382) argues that “in many respects the Japanese colonies developed in the manner suggested by the model”. In the case of Taiwan, exports to Japan only comprised around 20 per cent of total exports immediately after the Japanese occupation, but by the late 1930s this had risen to 88 per cent. Taiwanese exports were dominated by rice and sugar almost all of which went to Japan. Korea was already quite tightly tied to the Japanese economy in terms of both exports and imports by early in the twentieth century, and these tight links remained until the end of the 1930s (Table 11).
But other aspects of the colonial model fit the Korean experience less well. In particular, Korea never ran large export surpluses, either before or after the imposition of Japanese rule. Imports often exceeded exports by fifteen per cent or more. Given that the balance of trade in services was also negative, Korea was running current account deficits for most years from 1911 to 1938. These deficits were funded by transfers from the Japanese government, and after 1927 by increasing long-term capital inflows. Taiwan, by contrast, ran export surpluses consistently after the early twentieth century; after 1916, exports often exceeded imports by more than 30 per cent (Table 11). The current account of the balance of payments was in surplus in all years from 1915 to 1938; these surpluses funded outward capital flows back to Japan, either through loans from the Taiwanese central bank to firms in Japan, or through flows of reserve funds from the Taiwan government back to Japan (Mizoguchi and Umemura 1988: 295-98; Mizoguchi and Yamamoto 1984: 408-11).
Elsewhere in colonial South East Asia, most economies were running large surpluses on the balance of trade from the 1890s onwards. The main exceptions were the Philippines and French Indochina where, until 1915, the trade balance was frequently in deficit (Tables 12 and 13). However a surplus of exports over imports did not mean that the current account was necessarily in surplus, as the balance on services was almost always in deficit. We only have complete balance of payments estimates for two colonies for the period from 1890 to 1940, Indonesia and French Indochina. In both cases, when the balance of trade was large and positive, the current account balance was substantially lower. In Indonesia, on average the current account balance was positive for much of the period from 1901 to 1939 (Korthals Altes 1987: Table 1; Booth 1998: Table 5.5). In Indochina, the record was much more mixed. There were large inflows of capital in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries on both government and private account, mainly to develop infrastructure and to support the growing French bureaucratic presence (Bassino 2000a: Tables 2 and 3a). Current account surpluses were consistently positive and large only for the years from 1936 to 1944. It is probable that over these years outward remittances by the Chinese were an important factor driving the large surpluses (Bassino 2000a: 335).
The surpluses on the trade account recorded in the Philippines after 1915 were not as large as in Taiwan, and were probably largely offset by negative balances on services. Balance of payments estimates prepared by the American government for the decade from 1925 to 1934 indicate that for most years the deficit on services together with interest and dividend movements offset the positive balance of trade (United States Tariff Commission 1937: Table 8). In the Federated Malay States, large export surpluses were recorded for most years after 1900, but they were to some extent offset by deficits in other parts of British Malaya. When consolidated export and import data for all of British Malaya were published in the inter-war years, the export surplus was much lower, and as in the case of the Philippines, it was probably offset to some extent by deficits in services. In the case of Burma, where commodity export surpluses were consistently above 40 per cent from 1906 onwards, the current account was in all likelihood positive and used to finance outward remittances of Indian workers, and subventions by Burma to the British Indian government in Delhi[7].
There was also considerable variation within East and Southeast Asia by the 1930s in the degree of dependence of the colony on the metropole for imports and exports. While the two Japanese colonies were very dependent on Japan for both imports and exports, only one colony in South East Asia demonstrated similar dependence. That was the Philippines, where exports of sugar in particular benefited from preferential access to the American market (Table 11). Elsewhere the degree of dependence on the metropole was not as high, and in Indonesia it fell over the last four decades of Dutch colonial rule. The reason for the low dependence on metropolitan markets in both Indonesia and British Malaya by the late 1930s was the rising importance of other markets, especially the USA for two of their principal exports, rubber and tin. In the case of Burma, rice exports went largely to British India and to other parts of Asia.
In contrast to the Japanese colonies, where the export sectors were tethered tightly to the requirements of the metropolitan economy, the capitalist enterprises which controlled the main export industries in Indonesia, Malaya and French Indochina were concerned with selling to those markets where demand was highest. This was a risky strategy; when there was a downturn in world demand for staples such as rubber, tin and petroleum products as a result of the industrial slump of the 1930s, together with a rise in protectionism, many markets were severely curtailed. The worst affected colony was Indonesia. The Dutch home market was small and there was not a large Dutch empire in other parts of the world to absorb Indonesian exports of sugar, rubber, tin and petroleum products. The Philippines, which had quotas for its sugar exports in the American market was more fortunate, and in this respect resembled the two Japanese colonies.
Trends in living standards in colonial Asia
A frequent criticism made of many colonial economic systems in Asia and elsewhere is that the economic growth which occurred did not benefit the great majority of the population. While exports may have boomed, and government revenues expanded, nutritional intakes for the mass of the population did not improve, access to health care and secular education was severely limited, and as a result mortality rates were high, and many people were illiterate. Wage labour opportunities were limited, and wage rates were low. In Korea where criticism of the impact of colonial policies on welfare has been especially strong, it has been argued that by the 1930s, “pauperization among Korean farmers was becoming increasingly a pressing problem even for the colonial policy makers” (Chang 1971: 176). In spite of some progress in the adoption of new production technologies, rice consumption per capita fell steadily from 1912 to 1930, forcing the great majority of the population to eat more inferior foods such as millet (Lee 1936: 275). Although there was some improvement in rice availability towards the end of the 1930s, total grain availability per capita was still in 1937-41 well below the average for 1912-16 (Johnston 1953: 55).
The fall in domestic rice availability in Korea after 1910 has been explained by the increase in the proportion of arable land controlled by large-scale commercial owners, many of them Japanese. Rents were often paid in kind, so that a high percentage of the rice crop passed to landlords and then into the export market (Johnston 1953: 55). By 1938, over half of all farmers in Korea were tenants who did not own any land (Grajdanzev 1944: 109: Myers and Yamada 1984: 451-2). Myers and Yamada argue that the “dysfunctions” in Korean agriculture (especially regarding access to land) were much greater than in Taiwan, where rural living standards appear to have been higher by the late 1930s. Certainly rice availability per capita was higher in Taiwan (Table 6). However Gill (1998: 133) suggests that it was not so much coercion as the well organised export marketing networks which encouraged both landlords and tenants in Korea to sell rice to the Japanese rather than the local market. He also argues that changing relative prices might have induced Koreans to switch from purchases of calories to other goods.
Several authors have used anthropometric evidence to examine trends in living standards in both Korea and Taiwan during the Japanese colonial period. In Korea, Gill (1998: 124-6) claims that the Korean population became shorter beginning with the birth cohorts of the late 1920s, and a secular growth in height only began with birth cohorts from the early 1950s. He argues that reduced grain consumption explained at least part of the decline in the colonial period. In Taiwan by contrast, Morgan and Liu (2005) argue that rural food intake and per capita incomes improved from the 1910s to the 1940s, and this in turn led to an increase in male heights. Ka (1995: 144) argues that rural living standards in the 1930s in Taiwan underwent “substantive growth”; he cited the estimates of Mizoguchi (1972: Table 3) on rising real wages, in both manufacturing and agriculture. On the other hand, Chang’s analysis of farm household surveys in Taiwan over the 1930s indicated some decline in rice consumption per capita between 1931 and 1937, although there was a sharp increase in intake of sweet potatoes (Chang 1969: Table 14). Chang explains this switch in terms of movements in relative prices; real per capita expenditures of farm families between 1931 and 1937, according to his estimates, increased by around 12 per cent.
Turning to South East Asia, it is striking how much variation there was by the end of the 1930s in per capita rice availability (Table 6). In Java, per capita availability of rice was only 85 kg by 1937-39, and in the Philippines 97 kg, which was slightly higher than in Korea. This contrasts with 181 kg in Thailand, and 140kg in Indochina. In both Java and the Philippines, calorie intake was augmented by other foods including corn, cassava and sweet potatoes. The time series produced by Mears (1961: 248) on rice availability in Java shows some fluctuation between 1921 and 1941, but no discernible upward trend. In the Philippines, the series on rice and corn availability produced by Mears et al (1974: 355-57) showed increases in per capita terms until the mid-1920s, and then some decline. A study of living standards in the Ilocos region of northern Luzon in the 1930s by Lava (1938: 24) found that families of five (three adults and two children) were subsisting on 5,700 calories per day, which was well below minimum recommended intakes. An examination of living standards among sugar workers and found that the typical family “spends almost the entire income for food and clothing of the lowest quality and quantity” (Runes 1939: 30). Although Lava (1938: 81) conceded that “actual stark starvation does not exist in the Philippines except in isolated cases” and that living standards in the Philippines could have been higher than in parts of Japan, both his study and that of Runes cautioned against any casual assumption that the population of the Philippines had shared equally in the fruits of the economic development which had occurred in the American era. Indeed Kurihara (1945: 40) quotes some authors who argued that the living standards of many in the Philippines in the late 1930s were little better than in the last phase of Spanish rule.
These arguments contrast with the assertion of Williamson (2000: 23) that living standards in the Philippines doubled under the American occupation. The only evidence adduced to support this claim is a series on real wages which shows a steady rise from the latter part of the 1890s to the early 1920s, and then some decline, although real wages more than doubled between 1895-99 and 1935-39 (Williamson 2000: Table 1.2). He argues that real wages in the Philippines were 80 per cent higher than those in Japan in 1920-24, and more or less the same as in Japan by 1935-39. After 1910, real wages in the Philippines were higher than in either Korea or Taiwan, or in Thailand and Indonesia[8]. Space precludes a thorough critique of these data here; the main point to make is that it is very difficult to compare real wages across countries, partly because labour markets operate in different ways, partly because series on (for example) agricultural wages are not always comparable and partly because inadequate attention is often paid to differences in purchasing power of currencies, across countries and over time.
Demographic indicators are probably a more reliable guide to changes in living standards over time than wage data. We do not have long time series on, for example, infant mortality rates for all parts of East and South East Asia for the early part of the twentieth century, but we do have figures for most countries by the 1930s. It seems clear that infant mortality rates were lower in Taiwan, the Philippines and British Malaya than in Indonesia, Indochina and Burma (Table 14). The data on crude death rates (which are probably less reliable, as they are derived from registration data) tell a similar story. There can be little doubt that infant mortality rates and crude death rates fell in Taiwan over the Japanese period, and life expectancy increased (Barclay 1954: Tables 36, 37 and 39). Kimura (1993: 643) argues that there was also a decline in death rates in Korea after 1920. In the Philippines there was also some decline in both indicators over the American period (Zablan 1978: Tables 79 and 90). Banens (2000: Table 7) shows a decline in infant mortality rates among the Vietnamese population in Hanoi between 1925 and 1938, admittedly from a very high level, while in British Malaya, Vlieland (1932: 110) estimates a fall of around a third in the Straits Settlements between 1911 and 1931. No doubt in all cases, colonial governments would have attributed these declines to better access to modern health facilities, and especially in urban areas, to better provision of sanitation and clean drinking water[9].
Taiwan’s Presidential Office was originally the Office of the Governor-General
in the Japanese colonial government
The final set of welfare indicators relate to education. Here the differences between colonies were quite stark by the 1930s. In spite of the assertions of authors such as Maddison (1990: 365) that the Japanese were more successful in increasing access to education than the other colonial powers, the evidence indicates that neither in Taiwan nor in Korea did the Japanese surpass the American achievement in the Philippines. By 1940/41 it was estimated that just over two million students were enrolled in public schools in the Philippines, and a further 180,000 in private schools. Of these a remarkable 40,000 were in post-secondary institutions, a much larger figure than in Korea or Taiwan, or in any European colony (Bureau of Census and Statistics 1960: 21-29). In Korea, tertiary enrolments were much lower, and a high proportion of the students were Japanese (Kim 1985: 168). In Taiwan, the Taihoku Imperial University was established largely for research purposes, and few Taiwanese students were accepted. The ten specialised middle schools, which were located in the cities and large towns, were open to all Japanese boys, but only a few carefully selected Taiwanese (Kerr 1942: 53). The Japanese government in Taiwan did much more in developing primary education, but until the end of Japanese rule, almost all Taiwanese were denied access to higher education, and the jobs which required tertiary qualifications. In both Korea and Taiwan, the goal of the Japanese educational system was only to “fashion the lower track of the two-track Meiji education system” (Tsurumi 1984: 308).
The Philippines and Taiwan were well ahead of most other parts of East and South East Asia in terms of the ratio of educational enrolments to total population by the end of the 1930s (Table 14). At the other end of the scale was Indochina; both here and in the Netherlands Indies, provision of education to the indigenous population was very limited. In British Malaya the ratio was above that of Korea, although there a disproportionate number of students were Chinese and Indian rather than Malay. The “plural society” which had been created by large-scale in-migration from China and India to Malaya, Burma and Indonesia had led to a skewed access to education by race. Correcting this bias proved to be a major challenge for post-independence governments.
Conclusions
To return to the question posed at the beginning of this paper, was there already clear evidence by the late 1930s that Korea and Taiwan had benefited from Japanese “developmental colonialism” to a greater extent than elsewhere in Asia? In fact, it would appear from Table 14 that if a composite index of human development were to be constructed for 1938 on the basis of per capita GDP, demographic data and educational enrolments, the Philippines would have come out on top. [10] Taiwan would certainly have been second; if we allow for the probable understatement of per capita GDP in the Maddison data, Taiwan may have been top of the rankings, or first equal with the Philippines. Although both Korea and Malaya had higher per capita GDP, and similar demographic data, they scored less well than both Taiwan and the Philippines on educational enrolments. It is likely that French Indochina would have come bottom followed by Burma and Indonesia. Although per capita GDP was relatively low in Thailand, crude death rates were lower and enrolments higher than in French Indochina, Burma, or Indonesia. [11]
It may well have surprised the Philippine government in the late 1930s to have learnt of its top slot. Senior officials were conscious that in several sectors, especially agriculture, other parts of South East Asia were technically more advanced.[12] As we have seen, surveys carried out in the late 1930s showed that many Philippinos were very poor, and that many of the gains from American rule had accrued to a small urban middle class. It was, to a considerable extent, their children who had benefited from the expansion of secondary and tertiary education. Critics of American rule have pointed out that the result of American policies was to entrench this class in business, the professions, in senior government positions and in politics, where they remain dominant to the present day. American rule “did little to transform the existing Philippine power structures” (Kang 2002: 27). Elsewhere in East and South East Asia the colonial legacy may have been more meagre, and the process of decolonisation more violent and prolonged, but the new elites which assumed power after 1950 have in several cases proved more effective in promoting rapid economic development.
Those who want to defend Japanese “developmental colonialism” can point to the achievements of the Japanese in transferring Japanese rice technology to both Taiwan and Korea, and to the impressive improvements in physical infrastructure in both colonies. But were these achievements really enough to establish the foundations for the transformation of both Taiwan and the Republic of Korea after 1950? On the negative side, critics can point to the large balance of payments surpluses which accumulated in Taiwan, and which fuelled the high level of remittances back to Japan. The mechanisms by which these transfers occurred have yet to be elucidated in detail, at least in the English-language literature. But it seems that the protectionist regime which the Japanese established within their empire led to higher prices for agricultural products, such as rice and sugar, than would have prevailed in a free-trade regime. The ultimate costs for Japanese colonial policies in both Korea and Taiwan were borne by consumers in both the colonies and in metropolitan Japan, who had to pay higher prices for commodities such as rice and sugar, compared with consumers in Southeast Asia, and in other parts of the world. [13]
Much work remains to be done on the full economic impact of different colonial systems in Asia in the first part of the twentieth century. What I have tried to establish in this paper is that the case for Japanese exceptionalism is far from proven, at least until the late 1930s. Arguably a full assessment of the Japanese legacy should continue at least until 1945, and should probably also take into account the post-war developments in both Taiwan and the Korean peninsula. This would involve an evaluation of the ambitious Japanese plans to promote industrial growth in Korea and Manchuria and also of the full impact of the Japanese military occupation on the economies of Southeast Asia. Such an assessment is beyond the scope of this paper. In addition more work needs to be done on policy-making in the former colonies in the crucial post-1945 period. Those who argue that it was post-colonial policies, including comprehensive land reform and rapid increases in educational provision, as well as reforms in the trade regime, which were crucial in transforming both Taiwan and Korea, especially the south, in the 1950s and beyond would appear to have a strong case. But why were such policies not pursued with the same vigour in Southeast Asia? This is the crucial question which needs much more research.
This article was written for Japan Focus. Posted on May 7, 2007.
Notes:
[1]. Versions of this paper have been presented in seminars in London, Melbourne, Canberra, Singapore and Tokyo. I am very grateful to participants for many helpful suggestions, and to two referees; I accept full responsibility for all remaining errors of fact and interpretation.
[2] I cannot claim to be the first to have compared Japanese colonialism with that in other parts of Asia. Cumings (1999) examines the Japanese legacy in Korea with that of the French in Indochina while Kang (2002) compares Korea and the Philippines. I try to look at both Korea and Taiwan in a broader South East Asian perspective.
[3] It should be noted that the Maddison data have been challenged by Fukao, Ma and Yuan (2005) who argue that his method of adjusting GDP data for differences in purchasing power was faulty for Japan, Taiwan and Korea. They argue that Korean real per capita GDP was lower in relation to that of Japan, and Taiwan real per capita GDP higher, than is indicated in Table 2.
[4] Eckert (1996: 14-27) examines the evidence on economic and social change in Korea after 1930, which he argues is little researched and still very controversial. He points out that the opportunities for Korean workers to climb the skill ladder in industry were very limited, but does not address the employment of women.
[5] On the demise of revenue farming across South East Asia, see the various essays in Butcher and Dick (1993). It should be noted that the Philippines was a partial exception to the trend towards centralisation, in that the American administration wished to encourage the emergence of strong local government (Hutchcroft 2000), although Luton (1971) argues that in some respects the fiscal system became more centralised after 1900.
[6] Kimura (1989: 303) argues that the land tax in Korea was in theory a proportional tax, but in practice “fundamentally regressive”. This contrasts with the situation in Java, where by the inter-war years the land tax was a tax on the presumptive income from agricultural land and broadly progressive in its incidence (Furnivall 1934)
[7] See Shein Maung et al (1969) for an analysis of the provincial contract system and its implications for Burma.
[8] Williamson appears to be using an urban wage series, and urban-rural wage differentials by 1918 were substantial; see Doeppers (1984), pp. 39-41. In the late 1930s, a minimum wage was imposed in urban labour markets for public sector workers which would have further widened urban-rural differentials; see Kurihara (1945), pp. 42-43.
[9] Infant mortality rates were often higher in urban than rural areas, probably due to lack of clean water, and poor sanitation. Gooszen (1999: 192-3) cites Dutch research which found very high infant mortality of more than 400 per thousand in parts of Batavia (Jakarta) in 1917-19, which were similar to those reported by Banens (2000: 36) for Hanoi. Vlieland (1932:110) found that infant mortality rates in urban Singapore were higher than in the more rural Federated Malay States.
[10] If the Maddison data understate per capita GDP in Taiwan relative to Korea, then Taiwan would probably be first equal with the Philippines.
[11] The lack of reliable data on life expectancies and literacy for several parts of East and Southeast Asia make the computation of a Human Development Index (HDI) for the late 1930s difficult. An HDI has been computed by Metzer (1998: 57) for 36 countries in the late 1930s which puts the Philippines at 22, above most Latin American countries, with the exception of Chile. Thailand was ranked at 26, and India botton at 36. No other Asian country was included in Metzer’s estimates.
[12] Davis (1932: 23-8) stressed the gap in yields of rice and sugar between Luzon and Java, and the more advanced development of experimental stations for sugar in Java, and rubber in Sumatra and Malaya. He also stressed that the Philippines was “backward in adopting a definite plan of development extending over a period of years and in consistently carrying out that plan”. Davis was a Republican appointment as Governor General.
[13] See Anderson and Tyers (1992) for a deeper analysis of the welfare effects of Japanese rice policy in the inter-war years.
Bibliography:
Amsden, Alice (1985), “The State and Taiwan‘s Economic Development” in Peter B. Evans, D. Rueschemeyer and T. Skopcol (Editors), Bringing the State Back In, New York: Cambridge University Press
Anderson, Kym and Rod Tyers (1992), “Japanese rice policy in the interwar period: Some consequences of imperial self-sufficiency”, Japan and the World Economy, 4, 103-127
Andrus, J.R. (1948), Burmese Economic Life, Stanford: Stanford University Press
Aye Hlaing (1965), An Economic and Statistical Analysis of Economic Development of Burma under British Rule, PhD Dissertation, University of London
Banens, Maks (2000), “Vietnam: A Reconstruction of its 20th Century Population History” in Jean-Pascal Bassino, Jean-Dominique Giacometti and K. Odaka (Editors), Quantitative Economic History of Vietnam 1900-1990, Tokyo: Hitotsubashi University, Institute of Economic Research
Bank of Chosen (1920), Economic History of Chosen, Seoul, Bank of Chosen
Barclay, George (1954), Colonial Development and Population in Taiwan, Princeton: Princeton University Press
Barker, Randolph, Robert Herdt and Beth Rose (1985), The Rice Economy of Asia, Washington: Resources for the Future
Barnett, H.L. (1947), Malayan Agricultural Statistics, Kuala Lumpur: Department of Agriculture
Bassino, Jean-Pascal (2000a), “Estimates of Indochina’s and Vietnam’s Balance of Payments, 1890-1945: Investigating the Extent of the French Drain in Vietnam” in Jean-Pascal Bassino, Jean-Dominique Giacometti and K. Odaka (Editors), Quantitative Economic History of Vietnam 1900-1990, Tokyo: Hitotsubashi University, Institute of Economic Research
Bassino, Jean-Pascal (2000b), “Public Finance in Vietnam under French rule, 1895-1954” in Jean-Pascal Bassino, Jean-Dominique Giacometti and K. Odaka (Editors), Quantitative Economic History of Vietnam 1900-1990, Tokyo: Hitotsubashi University, Institute of Economic Research
Bassino, Jean-Pascal and Bui Thi Lan Huong (2000), “Estimates of Indochina’s and Vietnam’s International Trade (1890-1946) in Jean-Pascal Bassino, Jean-Dominique Giacometti and K. Odaka (Editors), Quantitative Economic History of Vietnam 1900-1990, Tokyo: Hitotsubashi University, Institute of Economic Research
Birnberg, Thomas B. and Stephen A. Resnick (1975), Colonial Development: An Econometric Study, New Haven: Yale University Press
Booth, Anne (1998), The Indonesian Economy in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries: A History of Missed Opportunities, London: Macmillan
Booth, Anne (2003), “Four Colonies and a Kingdom: A Comparison of Fiscal, Trade and Exchange Rate Policies in South East Asia in the 1930s”, Modern Asian Studies, Vol 37 (2): 429-460.
Booth, Anne (2004), “Did colonial economic policies impede economic development? Some evidence from South East Asia”, London: SOAS Department of Economics (unpublished working paper)
Bureau of Census and Statistics (1941), Yearbook of Philippine Statistics 1940, Manila: Commonwealth of the Philippines, Bureau of Census and Statistics
Bureau of Census and Statistics (1947), Yearbook of Philippine Statistics 1946, Manila: Republic of the Philippines, Bureau of Census and Statistics
Bureau of Census and Statistics (1960), Handbook of Philippine Statistics, 1903-1959, Manila: Bureau of Census and Statistics
Butcher, John and Howard Dick (Editors) (1993), The Rise and Fall of Revenue Farming, London: Macmillan
Carr, Carolle and Ramon H. Myers (1973), “The Agricultural Transformation in Taiwan: the Case of Ponlai Rice, 1922-42” in R.T. Shand (Editor), Technical Change in Asian Agriculture, Canberra: Australian National University Press
Central Bureau of Statistics (1947), Statistical Pocketbook of Indonesia, 1941, Batavia: G. Kolff and Co.
Central Service of Statistics (1940), Statistical Yearbook of Thailand, 1937-38 and 1938-39, No. 20, Bangkok: Central Service of Statistics
Chang, Han-Yu (1969), “A Study of the Living Conditions of Farmers in Taiwan, 1931-1950”, The Developing Economies, Vol VII (1), pp. 35-62
Chang, Han-Yu and Ramon Myers (1963), “Japanese Colonial Development Policy in Taiwan, 1895-1906: A Case of Bureaucratic Entrepreneurship”, Journal of Asian Studies, Vol 22 (4), 433-49
Chang, Yunshik (1966), Population in Early Modernization: Korea, PhD Dissertation, Princeton University
Chang, Yunshik (1971), “Colonization as Planned Changed: The Korean Case”, Modern Asian Studies, Vol 5 (2), pp. 161-86
Creutzberg, P. (1975), Changing Economy of Indonesia, Vol 1, Indonesia’s Export Crops, 1816-1940, The Hague: Martinus Nijhoff
Creutzberg,P. (1976), Changing Economy of Indonesia, Vol 2, Public Finance: 1816-1939, The Hague: Martinus Nijhoff
Cumings, Bruce (1984a), “The Legacy of Japanese Colonialism in Korea” in Myers, Ramon H. and Mark R. Peattie (Editors) The Japanese Colonial Empire, 1895-1945, Princeton:Princeton University Press
Cumings, Bruce (1984b), “The origins and development of the Northeast Asian political economy: industrial sectors, product cycles, and political consequences”, International Organization, 38 (1), 1-40
Cumings, Bruce (1999), “Colonial Formations and deformations: Korea, Taiwan, and Vietnam” in Parallax Visions: making sense of American-East Asian Relations, Durham: Duke University Press
Davis, Dwight (1932), “Reports on Good Will Trip”, Appendix 1, Annual Report of the Governor General of the Philippine Islands 1931, Washington: United States Government Printing Office
Department of Economic Affairs (1947), Statistical Pocketbook of Indonesia 1941, Batavia: G. Kolff and Co.for the Central Bureau of Statistics
Department of Statistics (1939), Malayan Year Book 1939, Singapore: Government Printing Office for the Department of Statistics, Straits Settlements and Federated Malay States.
Direction des Services Economiques (1947), Annuaire Statistique de l’Indochine, 1943-1946(Hanoi, 1946
Doeppers, Daniel F. (1984), Manila 1900-1941: Social Change in a Late Colonial Metropolis, Quezon City: Ateneo de Manila University Press
Doumer, Paul A. (1902), Rapport: Situation de l’Indochine, 1897-1901, Hanoi: F-H Schneider
Eckert, Carter J. (1996), “Total War, Industrialisation, and Social Change in Late Colonial Korea“, in Peter Duus, Ramon H. Myers and Mark R. Peattie, The Japanese Wartime Empire, 1931-1945, Princeton: Princeton University Press
Emerson, Rupert (1937), Malaysia: A Study in Direct and Indirect Rule, New York: Macmillan
Eng, Pierre van der (1996), Agricultural Growth in Indonesia, Basingstoke: Macmillan Press
Eng, Pierre van der (2002), “Indonesia‘s Growth Performance in the 20th Century” in The Asian Economies in the Twentieth Centuries, Edited by A. Maddison, D. Rao and W. Shepherd,Cheltenham: Edward Elgar
Espino, Jose M. (1933), The American Tariff Policy in the Philippines, Manila: Institute of Pacific Relations
Evans, L.W. (1939), Federated Malay States, Report of the Registrar General of Births and Deaths for the year 1938, Kuala Lumpur: FMS Government Press
Fraser, H. (1939), Annual Report on the Social and Economic Progress of the People of the Federated Malay States for 1938, Kuala Lumpur, FMS Government Press
Fukao, Kyoji, Debin Ma and Tangjun Yuan (2005), “International Comparison in Historical Perspective: Reconstructing the 1934-36 Benchmark Purchasing Power Parity for Japan, Korea and Taiwan”, Discussion Paper Series 66, Tokyo: Hitotsubsashi University Research Unit for Statistical Analysis in Social Sciences.
Furnivall, J.S. (1934), Studies in the Social and Economic Development of the Netherlands East Indies, IIId, The Land Revenue System, Rangoon: Burma Book Club Ltd
Furnivall, J.S. (1943), Educational Progress in Southeast Asia, New York: Institute of Pacific Relations
Gill, Insong (1998), “Stature, Consumption, and the Standard of Living in Colonial Korea“, in John Komlos and Joerg Baten (Editors), The Biological Standard of Living in Comparative Perspective, Stuttgart: Franz Steiner Verlag
Gooszen, Hans (1999), A demographic history of the Indonesian archipelago, 1880-1942, Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies
Grajdanzev, Andrew J. (1942), Formosa Today: An Analysis of the Economic Development and Strategic Importance of Japan’s Tropical Colony, New York: Institute of Pacific Relations
Grajdanzev, Andrew J. (1944), Modern Korea, New York: Institute of Pacific Relations
Haggard, Stephan, David Kang and Chung-In Moon, “Japanese Colonialism and Korean Development: A Critique”, World Development, 25 (6), 867-81
Hayami, Yujiro (1973), “Development and Diffusion of High Yielding Rice Varieties in Japan, Korea and Taiwan, 1890-1940” R.T. Shand (Editor), Technical Change in Asian Agriculture, Canberra: Australian National University Press
Ho, Samuel Pao-san (1984), “Colonialism and Development: Korea, Taiwan, and Kwantung” in Myers, Ramon H. and Mark R. Peattie (Editors) The Japanese Colonial Empire, 1895-1945, Princeton: Princeton University Press
Hooley, Richard (1968), “Long-Term Growth of the Philippine Economy, 1902-1961”, The Philippine Economic Journal, Vol VII (1), pp. 1-24
Howe, Christopher (2001), “Taiwan in the 20th Century: Model or Victim? Development Problems in a Small Asian Economy”, China Quarterly, No. 165, pp. 37-60
Hutchcroft, Paul D. (2000), “Colonial Masters, National Politicos, and Provincial Lords: Central Authority and Local Autonomy in the American Philippines, 1900-1913”, Journal of Asian Studies, Vol 59 (2), May, pp. 277-306
Ingram, J (1971), Economic Change in Thailand, 1850-1970, Kuala Lumpur: Oxford University Press
Japan Statistical Association (1987), Historical Statistics of Japan, Volume 3 Tokyo: Japan Sttistical Association
Johnston, B. F. (1953), Japanese Food Management in World War II, Stanford: Stanford University Press
Ka, Chih-Ming (1995), Japanese Colonialism in Taiwan: Land Tenure, Development, and Dependency, 1895-1945, Boulder: Westview Press
Kang, David C. (2002), Crony Capitalism: Corruption and Development in South Korea and the Philippines, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Kerr, George H. (1942), “Formosa: Colonial Laboratory”, Far Eastern Survey, February 23. pp. 50-55
Kim, Jongchol (1985), Education and Development: Some Essays and Thoughts on Korean Education, Seoul: Seoul National University Press
Kimura, Mitsuhiko (1989), “Public Finance in Korea under Japanese Rule: Deficit in the Colonial Account and Colonial Taxation”, Explorations in Economic History, Vol 26, pp. 285-310
Kimura, Mitsuhiko (1993), “Standards of Living in Colonial Korea: Did the Masses become Worse Off or Better Off under Japanese Rule”, Journal of Economic History, Vol 53 (3), pp. 629-52
Kohli, Atul (1994), “Where Do High Growth Political Economies Come From? The Japanese Lineage of Korea’s “Developmental State”, World Development, 22 (9), pp. 1269-93
Kohli, Atul (2004), State-Directed Development: Political Power and Industrialization in the Global Periphery, Cambridge University Press
Korthals Altes, W.L. (1987), Changing Economy of Indonesia, Vol 7, Balance of Payments 1822-1939, Amsterdam: Royal Tropical Institute
Korthals Altes, W.L. (1991), Changing Economy of Indonesia, Vol 12a, General Trade Statistics 1822-1940, Amsterdam: Royal Tropical Institute
Kratoska, Paul H. (2000), “Imperial Unity versus Local Autonomy: British Malaya and the Depression in the 1930s” in Peter Boomgaard and Ian Brown (editors). Weathering the Storm: The Economies of Southeast Asia in the 1930s Depression, Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies
Kurihara, Kenneth (1945), Labor in the Philippine Economy, Stanford: Stanford University Press
Laanen, J.T.M. van (1980), Changing Economy in Indonesia, Volume 6 Money and Banking, 1816-1940, The Hague: Martinus Nijhoff
Lava, Horacio (1938), “Levels of Living in the Ilocos Region”, Study No 1, Philippine Council of the Institute of Pacific Relations, Manila: College of Business Administration, University of the Philippines
Lee, Hoon K. (1936), Land Utilization and Rural Economy in Korea, Chicago: University of Chicago Press
Lim, Chong-Yah (1967), Economic Development of Modern Malaya, Kuala Lumpur: Oxford University Press
Lin, Ching-yuan (1973), Industrialization in Taiwan, 1946-72, New York: Praeger Publishers
Luton, Harry (1971), “American Internal Revenue Policy in the Philippines to 1916” in Norman G. Owen (Editor), Compadre Colonialism: Studies on the Philippines under American Rule, Ann Arbor: Michigan Papers on South and Southeast Asia, Number 3
Maddison, Angus (1990), “The Colonial Burden: A Comparative Perspective” in Maurice Scott and Deepak Lal (Editors), Public Policy and Economic Development: Essays in Honour of Ian Little, Oxford: Oxford University Press
Maddison, Angus (2003), The World Economy: Historical Statistics, Paris: OECD Development Centre
Mears, Leon A. (1961), Rice Marketing in the Republic of Indonesia, Jakarta: Institute for Economic and Social Research, University of Indonesia
Mears, Leon, M. Agabin, T.L. Anden and R.C. Marquez (1974), The Rice Economy of the Philippines, Manila: University of the Philippines Press
Mertens, Walter (1978), “Population Census Data on Agricultural Activities in Indonesia, Majalah Demografi Indonesia, No 9, June
Metzer, Jacob (1998), The Divided Economy of Mandatory Palestine, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Mizoguchi, Toshiyuki (1972), “Consumer Prices and Real Wages in Taiwan and Korea under Japanese Rule”, Hitotsubashi Journal of Economics, 13, June, pp. 40-65
Mizoguchi, Toshiyuki (1974), “Foreign Trade in Taiwan and Korea under Japanese Rule”, Hitotsubashi Journal of Economics, 15, February, pp. 37-53
Mizoguchi, Toshiyuki and Mataji Umemura (1988), Basic Economic Statistics of Former Japanese Colonies, 1895-1938, Tokyo: Toyo Keizai Shinposhain
Mizoguchi,Toshiyuki and Yuzo Yamomoto (1984), “Capital Formation in Taiwan and Korea” in Myers, Ramon H. and Mark R. Peattie (Editors) The Japanese Colonial Empire, 1895-1945, Princeton:Princeton University Press
Morgan, Stephen and Shiyung Liu (2005), “Was Japanese Colonialism Good for the Taiwanese? Stature and the Standard of Living in Taiwan, 1895-1945”, Working paper, University of Melbourne
Morris, Morris D. (1963), “Towards a re-interpretation of Nineteenth Century Indian Economic History”, Journal of Economic History, Vol 23 (4), pp. 606-18
Myers, R.H. (1969), “Taiwan” in R.T. Shand, Agricultural Development in Asia, Canberra: Australian National University Press
Myers, Ramon H. (1970), “Agrarian Policy and Agricultural transformation: Mainland China and Taiwan 1895-1945”, Journal of the Institute of Chinese Studies of the Chinese University of Hong Kong, Vol III (2), pp. 521-42
Myers, Ramon H. and Adrienne Ching (1964), “Agricultural Development in Taiwan under Japanese Colonial Rule”, Journal of Asian Studies, Vol 23, August, pp. 555-570
Myers, Ramon H. and Mark R. Peattie (Editors) (1984), The Japanese Colonial Empire, 1895-1945, Princeton:Princeton University Press
Myers, Ramon and Saburo Yamada (1984), ” Agricultural Development in the Empire” in Myers, Ramon H. and Mark R. Peattie (Editors) The Japanese Colonial Empire, 1895-1945, Princeton:Princeton University Press
National Planning Commission (1960), A Study of the Social and Economic History of Burma (British Burma), Part VIII British Burma from the Rebellion of 1931 to the Japanese Invasion of 1941, Rangoon: National Planning Commission, Ministry of National Planning
Nitisastro, Widjojo (1970), Population Trends in Indonesia, Ithaca: Cornell University Press
Norlund, Irene (1991), “The French Empire, the colonial state in Vietnam and economic policy: 1885-1940, Australian Economic History Review, Vol XXXI (1), March, pp. 72-89
Office of the Prime Minister (1958), A Study of the Social and Economic History of Burma (British Burma), Part 6A, 1897-1913, Rangoon: Economic and Social Board, Office of the Prime Minister
Palmore, James A., Ramesh Chander and Dorothy Fernandez (1975), “The Demographic Situation in Malaysia“, East-West Population Institute, Reprint Series 70, Honolulu: University of Hawaii
Park, Soon-Won (1999), “Colonial Industrial Growth and the Emergence of the Korean Working Class” in Gi-Wool Shin and Michael Robinson (Editors), Colonial Modernity in Korea, Cambridge: Harvard University Asia Center
Paauw, Douglas S. and John C.H. Fei (1973), The Transition in Open Dualistic Economies: Theory and Southeast Asian Experience, New Haven: Yale University Press
Peattie, Mark R. (1984), “Introduction” in Myers, Ramon H. and Mark R. Peattie (Editors) The Japanese Colonial Empire, 1895-1945, Princeton:Princeton University Press.
Reddy, K.N. (1972), The Growth of Public Expenditure in India, 1872-1968, New Delhi: Sterling Publishers
Reynolds, Lloyd G. (1983), “The Spread of Economic Growth to the Third World: 1850-1980”, Journal of Economic Literature, Vol XXI, Sepember, pp. 941-80
Richter, Hazel (1976), “Burma’s Rice Surplus: Accounting for the Decline”, Working Paper No. 3, Canberra: Development Studies Centre, Australian National University
Robequain, Charles (1944), The Economic Development of French Indo-China, London: Oxford University Press
Rose, Beth (1985), Appendix to the Rice Economy of Asia, Washington: Resources for the Future
Runes, I.T. (1939), General Standards of Living and Wages of Workers in the Philippine Sugar Industry, Manila: Philippine Council, Institute of Pacific Relations
Saito, T. and Lee Kin Kiong (1999), Statistics on the Burmese Economy: The 19th and 20th Centuries, Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies
Schneider, Adam (1998), “The Taiwan Government-general and Prewar Japanese Economic Expansion in South China and Southeast Asia, 1900-1936” in Harald Fuess (Editor), The Japanese Empire in East Asia and Its Postwar Legacy, Munich: Iudicium Verlag
Schwulst, E.B. (1932), “Report on the Budget and Financial Policies of French Indo-China, Siam, Federated Malay States and the Netherlands East Indies” in Report of the Governor General of the Philippine Islands 1931, Washington: United States Government Printing Office, pp. 42-59
Service de la Statistique Generale (1947), Annuaire Statistique de l’Indochine, 1943-46, Hanoi: Imprimerie d’Extreme-Orient
Shein Maung, Myint Myint Thant and Tin Tin Sein (1969), ‘ “Provincial Contract System” of British Indian Empire, in Relation to Burma- A Case of Fiscal Exploitation’, Journal of the Burma Research Society, Vol LIII, December, pp. 1-27
Shepherd, Jack (1941), Industry in South East Asia, New York: Institute of Pacific Relations
Sompop Manarungsan (1989), Economic Development of Thailand, 1850-1950, PhD Dissertation, State University of Groningen
Suh, Sang-Chul (1978), Growth and Structural Changes in the Korean Economy, 1910-1940, Cambridge: Harvard University Press
Sundrum, R.M. (1957), “Population Statistics of Burma”, Economics Research Project, Statistical Paper No 3, Rangoon: Economics, Statistics and Commerce Departments, University of Rangoon
Thorbecke, Erik (1979), “Agricultural Development” in Walter Galenson (Editor), Economic Growth and Structural Change in Taiwan, Ithaca: Cornell University Press
Tsurumi, E. Patricia (1984), ” Colonial Education in Korea and Taiwan” in Myers, Ramon H. and Mark R. Peattie (Editors) The Japanese Colonial Empire, 1895-1945, Princeton: Princeton University Press
United States Tariff Commission (1937), “United States-Philippines Trade with special reference to the Philippine Independence Act and Other Recent Legislation”, Report 118, Washington: United States Government Printing Office
Vlieland, C.A. (1932), British Malaya: A Report on the 1931 Census and on Certain Problems of Vital Statistics, London: Crown Agents
Williamson, Jeffrey G. (2000), “Globalization, factor prices and living standards in Asia before 1940” in A.J.H. Latham and Heita Kawakatsu (Editors), Asia Pacific Dynamism, 1550-2000, London: Routledge
Woo, Jung-en (1991), Race to the Swift: State Finance in Korean Industrialisation, New York: Columbia University Press
Zablan, Z.C. (1978), “Trends and Differential in Mortality” in Population of the Philippines, Country Monograph Series No. 5, Bangkok, United Nations Economic Commission for Asia and the Pacific
var footnotes_data = [];
jQuery('.article_description sup').each(function(ind,el){
var number = jQuery(el).text().trim();
if(number){
number = number.replace(/[^0-9]/gi,'');
}
//console.log(number);
if(footnotes_data[number]){
jQuery(el).css({cursor:'pointer'}).addClass('ftnt');
jQuery(el).bind('click',{number:number},function(ev){
var html = jQuery('span.footnote_text_'+number).html();
jQuery('.floating_footnote').remove();
var f = jQuery('
var fi = jQuery('
jQuery('').addClass('floating_footnote_close').text('x').bind('click',function(e){
jQuery(this).closest('.floating_footnote').remove();
}).prependTo(fi);
f.slideDown(1000);
})
}
});
jQuery(window).scroll(function(){
jQuery('.floating_footnote').slideUp(1000);
});
Share with a colleague: